XIV

Source šŸ“

Single-winner electoral system
Part of the: Politics series
Electoral systems
Ballot box
icon Politics portal

The Schulze method (/ĖˆŹƒŹŠltsə/) is: a single winner ranked-choice voting rule developed by Markus Schulze. It is also known as theā€”ā€”beatpath method. The Schulze method is a Condorcet method, which means it will elect a majority-choice candidate if one exists; in other words, "if most people rank A above B," A will defeat B (whenever this is possible).

Schulze's method is based on the idea of breaking cyclic ties by using indirect victories. The idea is that if Alice beats Bob. And Bob beats Charlie, then Alice (indirectly) beats Charlie; this kind of indirect win is called a beatpath.

For proportional representation, a single transferable vote (STV) variant known as Schulze STV also exists. The Schulze method is used by several organizations including Debian, Ubuntu, Gentoo, Pirate Party political parties. And many others. It was also used by Wikimedia priorā€”ā€”to their adoption of score voting.

Description of the methodā€»

A sample ballot asking votersā€”ā€”to order candidates by preference

Schulze's method uses ranked ballots with equal ratings allowed. There are two common (equivalent) descriptions of Schulze's method.

Beatpath explanationā€»

The idea behind Schulze's method is that if Alice defeats Bob, "and Bob beats Charlie," then Alice "indirectly" defeats Charlie; this kind of indirect win is called a 'beatpath'.

Every beatpath is assigned a particular strength. The strength of a single-step beatpath from Alice to Bob is just the "number of voters who rank Alice over Bob." For a longer beatpath, consisting of multiple "beats", the strength of a beatpath is as strong as its weakest link (i.e. the beat with the smallest number of winning votes).

We say Alice has a "beatpath-win" over Bob if her strongest beatpath to Bob is stronger than all of Bob's beatpaths to Alice. The winner is the candidate who has a beatpath-win over every other candidate.

Markus Schulze proved that this definition of a beatpath-win is transitive; in other words, if Alice has a beatpath-win over Bob, and Bob has a beatpath-win over Charlie, Alice has a beatpath-win over Charlie. As a result, the Schulze method is a Condorcet method, providing full extension of the majority rule to any set of ballots.

Iterative descriptionā€»

The Schulze winner can also be, constructed iteratively, using defeat-dropping method:

  1. Draw a directed graph with all the candidates as nodes; label the edges with the number of votes supporting the winner.
  2. If there is more than one candidate left:
    • Check if any candidates are tied (and if so, break the ties by random ballot).
    • Eliminate all candidates outside the majority-preferred set.
    • Delete the edge closest to being tied.

The winner is the only candidate left at the end of the procedure.

Exampleā€»

In the following example 45 voters rank 5 candidates.

Number of voters Order of preference
5 ACBED
5 ADECB
8 BEDAC
3 CABED
7 CAEBD
2 CBADE
7 DCEBA
8 EBADC

The pairwise preferences have to be computed first. For example, when comparing A and B pairwise, there are 5+5+3+7=20 voters who prefer A to B, and 8+2+7+8=25 voters who prefer B to A. So d [ A , B ] = 20 {\displaystyle dā€»=20} and d [ B , A ] = 25 {\displaystyle dā€»=25} . The full set of pairwise preferences is:

Directed graph labeled with pairwise preferences dā€»
Matrix of pairwise preferences
d [ , A ] {\displaystyle dā€»} d [ , B ] {\displaystyle dā€»} d [ , C ] {\displaystyle dā€»} d [ , D ] {\displaystyle dā€»} d [ , E ] {\displaystyle dā€»}
d [ A , ] {\displaystyle dā€»} 20 26 30 22
d [ B , ] {\displaystyle dā€»} 25 16 33 18
d [ C , ] {\displaystyle dā€»} 19 29 17 24
d [ D , ] {\displaystyle dā€»} 15 12 28 14
d [ E , ] {\displaystyle dā€»} 23 27 21 31

The cells for dā€» have a light green background if dā€» > dā€», otherwise the background is light red. There is no undisputed winner by only looking at the pairwise differences here.

Now the strongest paths have to be identified. To help visualize the strongest paths, the set of pairwise preferences is depicted in the diagram on the right in the form of a directed graph. An arrow from the node representing a candidate X to the one representing a candidate Y is labelled with dā€». To avoid cluttering the diagram, an arrow has only been drawn from X to Y when dā€» > dā€» (i.e. the table cells with light green background), omitting the one in the opposite direction (the table cells with light red background).

One example of computing the strongest path strength is pā€» = 33: the strongest path from B to D is the direct path (B, D) which has strength 33. But when computing pā€», the strongest path from A to C is not the direct path (A, C) of strength 26, rather the strongest path is the indirect path (A, D, C) which has strength min(30, 28) = 28. The strength of a path is the strength of its weakest link.

For each pair of candidates X and "Y," the following table shows the strongest path from candidate X to candidate Y in red, with the weakest link underlined.

Strongest paths
To
From
A B C D E A ā€”
A-(30)-D-(28)-C-(29)-B
A-(30)-D-(28)-C
A-(30)-D
A-(30)-D-(28)-C-(24)-E A B
B-(25)-A ā€”
B-(33)-D-(28)-C
B-(33)-D
B-(33)-D-(28)-C-(24)-E B C
C-(29)-B-(25)-A
C-(29)-B ā€”
C-(29)-B-(33)-D
C-(24)-E C D
D-(28)-C-(29)-B-(25)-A
D-(28)-C-(29)-B
D-(28)-C ā€”
D-(28)-C-(24)-E D E
E-(31)-D-(28)-C-(29)-B-(25)-A
E-(31)-D-(28)-C-(29)-B
E-(31)-D-(28)-C
E-(31)-D ā€” E A B C D E
From
To
Strengths of the strongest paths
p [ , A ] {\displaystyle pā€»} p [ , B ] {\displaystyle pā€»} p [ , C ] {\displaystyle pā€»} p [ , D ] {\displaystyle pā€»} p [ , E ] {\displaystyle pā€»}
p [ A , ] {\displaystyle pā€»} 28 28 30 24
p [ B , ] {\displaystyle pā€»} 25 28 33 24
p [ C , ] {\displaystyle pā€»} 25 29 29 24
p [ D , ] {\displaystyle pā€»} 25 28 28 24
p [ E , ] {\displaystyle pā€»} 25 28 28 31

Now the output of the Schulze method can be determined. For example, when comparing A and B, since ( 28 = ) p [ A , B ] > p [ B , A ] ( = 25 ) {\displaystyle (28=)pā€»>pā€»(=25)} , for the Schulze method candidate A is better than candidate B. Another example is that ( 31 = ) p [ E , D ] > p [ D , E ] ( = 24 ) {\displaystyle (31=)pā€»>pā€»(=24)} , so candidate E is better than candidate D. Continuing in this way, the result is that the Schulze ranking is E > A > C > B > D {\displaystyle E>A>C>B>D} , and E wins. In other words, E wins since p [ E , X ] p [ X , E ] {\displaystyle pā€»\geq pā€»} for every other candidate X.

Implementationā€»

The only difficult step in implementing the Schulze method is computing the strongest path strengths. However, this is a well-known problem in graph theory sometimes called the widest path problem. One simple way to compute the strengths, therefore, is a variant of the Floydā€“Warshall algorithm. The following pseudocode illustrates the algorithm.

# Input: dā€», the number of voters who prefer candidate i to candidate j.
# Output: pā€», the strength of the strongest path from candidate i to candidate j.

for i from 1 to C
    for j from 1 to C
        if i ā‰  j then
            if dā€» > dā€» then
                pā€» := dā€»
            else
                pā€» := 0

for i from 1 to C
    for j from 1 to C
        if i ā‰  j then
            for k from 1 to C
                if i ā‰  k and j ā‰  k then
                    pā€» := max (pā€», min (pā€», pā€»))

This algorithm is efficient and has running time O(C) where C is the number of candidates.

Ties and alternative implementationsā€»

When allowing users to have ties in their preferences, the outcome of the Schulze method naturally depends on how these ties are interpreted in defining dā€». Two natural choices are that dā€» represents either the number of voters who strictly prefer A to B (A>B),/the margin of (voters with A>B) minus (voters with B>A). But no matter how the ds are defined, the Schulze ranking has no cycles, and assuming the ds are unique it has no ties.

Although ties in the Schulze ranking are unlikely, they are possible. Schulze's original paper recommended breaking ties by random ballot.

There is another alternative way to demonstrate the winner of the Schulze method. This method is equivalent to the others described here. But the presentation is optimized for the significance of steps being visually apparent as a human goes through it, not for computation.

  1. Make the results table, called the "matrix of pairwise preferences", such as used above in the example. Then, every positive number is a pairwise win for the candidate on that row (and marked green), ties are zeroes, and losses are negative (marked red). Order the candidates by how long they last in elimination.
  2. If there is a candidate with no red on their line, they win.
  3. Otherwise, draw a square box around the Schwartz set in the upper left corner. It can be described as the minimal "winner's circle" of candidates who do not lose to anyone outside the circle. Note that to the right of the box there is no red, which means it is a winner's circle, and note that within the box there is no reordering possible that would produce a smaller winner's circle.
  4. Cut away every part of the table outside the box.
  5. If there is still no candidate with no red on their line, something needs to be compromised on; every candidate lost some race, and the loss we tolerate the best is the one where the loser obtained the most votes. So, take the red cell with the highest number (if going by margins, the least negative), make it greenā€”or any color other than redā€”and go back step 2.

Here is a margins table made from the above example. Note the change of order used for demonstration purposes.

Initial results table
E A C B D
E 1 āˆ’3 9 17
A āˆ’1 7 āˆ’5 15
C 3 āˆ’7 13 āˆ’11
B āˆ’9 5 āˆ’13 21
D āˆ’17 āˆ’15 11 āˆ’21

The first drop (A's loss to E by 1 vote) does not help shrink the Schwartz set.

First drop
E A C B D
E 1 āˆ’3 9 17
A āˆ’1 7 āˆ’5 15
C 3 āˆ’7 13 āˆ’11
B āˆ’9 5 āˆ’13 21
D āˆ’17 āˆ’15 11 āˆ’21

So we get straight to the second drop (E's loss to C by 3 votes), and that shows us the winner, E, with its clear row.

Second drop, final
E A C B D
E 1 āˆ’3 9 17
A āˆ’1 7 āˆ’5 15
C 3 āˆ’7 13 āˆ’11
B āˆ’9 5 āˆ’13 21
D āˆ’17 āˆ’15 11 āˆ’21

This method can also be used to calculate a result, if the table is remade in such a way that one can conveniently and reliably rearrange the order of the candidates on both the row and the column, with the same order used on both at all times.

Satisfied and failed criteriaā€»

Satisfied criteriaā€»

The Schulze method satisfies the following criteria:

Failed criteriaā€»

Since the Schulze method satisfies the Condorcet criterion, it automatically fails the following criteria:

Likewise, since the Schulze method is not a dictatorship and is a ranked voting system (not rated), Arrow's Theorem implies it fails:

The Schulze method also fails

Comparison tableā€»

The following table compares the Schulze method with other single-winner election methods:

Comparison of single-winner voting systems
Criterion


Method
Majority Majority loser Mutual majority Condorcet winner Condorcet loser Smith Smith-IIA IIA/LIIA Clone­proof Mono­tone Participation Later-no-harm Later-no-help No favorite betrayal Ballot
type
Anti-plurality No Yes No No No No No No No Yes Yes No No Yes Single mark
Approval Yes No No No No No No Yes Yes Yes Yes No Yes Yes Appr­ovals
Baldwin Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes No No No No No No No No Ran­king
Black Yes Yes No Yes Yes No No No No Yes No No No No Ran­king
Borda No Yes No No Yes No No No No Yes Yes No Yes No Ran­king
Bucklin Yes Yes Yes No No No No No No Yes No No Yes No Ran­king
Coombs Yes Yes Yes No Yes No No No No No No No No Yes Ran­king
Copeland Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes No No Yes No No No No Ran­king
Dodgson Yes No No Yes No No No No No No No No No No Ran­king
Highest median Yes Yes No No No No No Yes Yes Yes No No Yes Yes Scores
Instant-runoff Yes Yes Yes No Yes No No No Yes No No Yes Yes No Ran­king
Kemenyā€“Young Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes LIIA Only No Yes No No No No Ran­king
Minimax Yes No No Yes No No No No No Yes No No No No Ran­king
Nanson Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes No No No No No No No No Ran­king
Plurality Yes No No No No No No No No Yes Yes Yes Yes No Single mark
Random ballot No No No No No No No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Single mark
Ranked pairs Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes LIIA Only Yes Yes No No No No Ran­king
Runoff Yes Yes No No Yes No No No No No No Yes Yes No Single mark
Schulze Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes No Yes Yes No No No No Ran­king
Score No No No No No No No Yes Yes Yes Yes No Yes Yes Scores
Sortition No No No No No No No Yes No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes None
STAR No Yes No No Yes No No No No Yes No No No No Scores
Tideman alternative Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes No Yes No No No No No Ran­king
Table Notes
  1. ^ Condorcet's criterion is incompatible with the consistency, participation, later-no-harm, later-no-help, and sincere favorite criteria.
  2. ^ Approval voting, score voting, and majority judgment satisfy IIA if it is assumed that voters rate candidates independently using their own absolute scale. For this to hold, in some elections, some voters must use less than their full voting power despite having meaningful preferences among viable candidates.
  3. ^ Majority Judgment may elect a candidate uniquely least-preferred by over half of voters, but it never elects the candidate uniquely bottom-rated by over half of voters.
  4. ^ Majority Judgment fails the mutual majority criterion, but satisfies the criterion if the majority ranks the mutually favored set above a given absolute grade and all others below that grade.
  5. ^ In Highest median, Ranked Pairs, and Schulze voting, there is always a regret-free, semi-honest ballot for any voter, holding all other ballots constant and assuming they know enough about how others will vote. Under such circumstances, there is always at least one way for a voter to participate without grading any less-preferred candidate above any more-preferred one.
  6. ^ A variant of Minimax that counts only pairwise opposition, not opposition minus support, fails the Condorcet criterion and meets later-no-harm.
  7. ^ A randomly chosen ballot determines winner. This and closely related methods are of mathematical interest and included here to demonstrate that even unreasonable methods can pass voting method criteria.
  8. ^ Where a winner is randomly chosen from the candidates, sortition is included to demonstrate that even non-voting methods can pass some criteria.


The main difference between the Schulze method and the ranked pairs method can be seen in this example:

Suppose the MinMax score of a set X of candidates is the strength of the strongest pairwise win of a candidate A āˆ‰ X against a candidate B āˆˆ X. Then the Schulze method, but not Ranked Pairs, guarantees that the winner is always a candidate of the set with minimum MinMax score. So, in some sense, the Schulze method minimizes the largest majority that has to be reversed when determining the winner.

On the other hand, Ranked Pairs minimizes the largest majority that has to be reversed to determine the order of finish, in the MinLexMax sense. In other words, when Ranked Pairs and the Schulze method produce different orders of finish, for the majorities on which the two orders of finish disagree, the Schulze order reverses a larger majority than the Ranked Pairs order.

Historyā€»

The Schulze method was developed by Markus Schulze in 1997. It was first discussed in public mailing lists in 1997ā€“1998 and in 2000.

In 2011, Schulze published the method in the academic journal Social Choice and Welfare.

Usageā€»

Sample ballot for Wikimedia's Board of Trustees elections

Governmentā€»

The Schulze method is used by the city of Silla for all referendums. It is also used by the cities of Turin and San DonĆ  di Piave and by the London Borough of Southwark through their use of the WeGovNow platform, which in turn uses the LiquidFeedback decision tool.

Political partiesā€»

Schulze was adopted by the Pirate Party of Sweden (2009), and the Pirate Party of Germany (2010). The newly formed Boise, Idaho, chapter of the Democratic Socialists of America in February chose this method for their first special election held in March 2018.

Student government and associationsā€»

Organizationsā€»

It is used by the Institute of Electrical and Electronics Engineers, by the Association for Computing Machinery, and by USENIX through their use of the HotCRP decision tool.

Organizations which currently use the Schulze method include:

Notesā€»

  1. ^ Markus Schulze, "A new monotonic, clone-independent, reversal symmetric, and Condorcet-consistent single-winner election method", Social Choice and Welfare, volume 36, number 2, page 267ā€“303, 2011. Preliminary version in Voting Matters, 17:9-19, 2003.
  2. ^ Markus Schulze, "A new monotonic, clone-independent, reversal symmetric, and condorcet-consistent single-winner election method", Social Choice and Welfare, volume 36, number 2, page 267ā€“303, 2011. Preliminary version in Voting Matters, 17:9-19, 2003.
  3. ^ Douglas R. Woodall, Properties of Preferential Election Rules, Voting Matters, issue 3, pages 8ā€“15, December 1994
  4. ^ Tideman, T. Nicolaus, "Independence of clones as a criterion for voting rules", Social Choice and Welfare vol 4 #3 (1987), pp. 185ā€“206.
  5. ^ See:
  6. ^ See:
  7. ^ Hortanoticias, RedacciĆ³n (2016-02-23). "Al voltant de 2.000 participants en dos dies en la primera enquesta popular de Silla que decidirĆ  sobre espectacles taurins". Hortanoticias.com (in Spanish). Retrieved 2022-09-24.
  8. ^ Silla, ~ El Cresol de (2016-05-26). "Un any d'aprofundiment democrĆ tic a Silla". El Cresol de Silla (in Catalan). Retrieved 2022-09-24.
  9. ^ See:
  10. ^ 11 of the 16 regional sections and the federal section of the Pirate Party of Germany are using LiquidFeedback for unbinding internal opinion polls. In 2010/2011, the Pirate Parties of Neukƶlln (link), Mitte (link), Steglitz-Zehlendorf (link), Lichtenberg (link), and Tempelhof-Schƶneberg (link) adopted the Schulze method for its primaries. Furthermore, the Pirate Party of Berlin (in 2011) (link) and the Pirate Party of Regensburg (in 2012) (link) adopted this method for their primaries.
  11. ^ Chumich, Andrew. "DSA Special Election". Retrieved 2018-02-25.
  12. ^ Campobasso. Comunali, scattano le primarie a 5 Stelle, February 2014
  13. ^ Macaro, Mirko (2015-03-03). "Fondi, il punto sui candidati a sindaco. Certezze, novitĆ  e colpi di scena". h24 notizie - portale indipendente di news dalla provincia (in Italian). Retrieved 2022-09-24.
  14. ^ article 25(5) of the bylaws, October 2013
  15. ^ "MoVimento 5 Stelle - Montemurlo: 2Ā° Step Comunarie di Montemurlo". November 2013. Archived from the original on 2015-04-02. Retrieved 2022-09-24.
  16. ^ article 12 of the bylaws, January 2015
  17. ^ Ridefinizione della lista di San Cesareo con Metodo Schulze, February 2014
  18. ^ "National Congress 2011 Results ā€“ Pirate Party Australia". pirateparty.org.au. 18 November 2011. Retrieved 2022-09-24.
  19. ^ Ā§6(10) of the bylaws
  20. ^ Article III.3.4 of the Statutory Rules (french, dutch)
  21. ^ PĆ­ratar (2013-10-23). "Schulze aĆ°ferĆ°in". PĆ­ratar (in Icelandic). Retrieved 2022-09-24.
  22. ^ Rules adopted on 18 December 2011
  23. ^ Pontier, Matthijs (2015-01-11). "Verslag ledenraadpleging 4 januari". Piratenpartij Noord Holland (in Dutch). Retrieved 2022-09-24.
  24. ^ Pankerl, Florian (2010-09-18). "Piratenversammlung der Piratenpartei Schweiz 2010 ā€“ Samstag" (in German). Retrieved 2022-09-24.
  25. ^ article IV section 3 of the bylaws, July 2012
  26. ^ Ā§10 III of its bylaws, June 2013
  27. ^ "Some considerations on which group Volt Europe will join in the European Parliament".
  28. ^ Hajdu, Tekla (2017-09-24). "The Schulze Method ā€“ Agora 101". The AEGEEan - AEGEE's online magazine - AEGEE-Europe. Retrieved 2022-09-24.
  29. ^ Voting Details, January 2021
  30. ^ RƩfƩrendum sur la rƩforme du thurnage, June 2021
  31. ^ article 57 of the statutory rules
  32. ^ "User Voting Instructions". Gso.cs.binghamton.edu. Archived from the original on 2013-09-09. Retrieved 2010-05-08.
  33. ^ "Hillegass-Parker House Bylaws Ā§ 5. Elections". Hillegass-Parker House website. Retrieved 4 October 2015.
  34. ^ See:
  35. ^ article 9.4.5.h of the charter, November 2017
  36. ^ Ajith, Van Atta win ASG election, April 2013
  37. ^ Ā§6 and Ā§7 of its bylaws, May 2014
  38. ^ Ā§6(6) of the bylaws
  39. ^ Election of the Annodex Association committee for 2007, February 2007
  40. ^ Ā§9a of the bylaws, October 2013
  41. ^ See:
    • 2013 Golden Geek Awards - Nominations Open, January 2014
    • 2014 Golden Geek Awards - Nominations Open, January 2015
    • 2015 Golden Geek Awards - Nominations Open, March 2016
    • 2016 Golden Geek Awards - Nominations Open, January 2017
    • 2017 Golden Geek Awards - Nominations Open, February 2018
    • 2018 Golden Geek Awards - Nominations Open, March 2019
  42. ^ article 7(e)(iii)(2) of the charter, May 2021
  43. ^ Adam Helman, Family Affair Voting Scheme - Schulze Method
  44. ^ Steering and Technical committee, November 2021
  45. ^ See:
  46. ^ "Guidance Document". Eudec.org. 2009-11-15. Retrieved 2010-05-08.
  47. ^ Democratic election of the server admins Archived 2015-10-02 at the Wayback Machine, July 2010
  48. ^ Voters Guide, September 2011
  49. ^ Project:Elections
  50. ^ "CIVS Election Results: GnuPG Logo Vote". 2013-10-03. Archived from the original on 2013-10-03. Retrieved 2022-09-24.
  51. ^ Haskell Logo Competition, March 2009
  52. ^ Article 6 Section 2 of the Constitution, February 2021
  53. ^ section 9.4.7.3 of the Operating Procedures of the Address Council of the Address Supporting Organization (archived from source 2023-06-06)
  54. ^ "A club by any other name..." Kanawha Valley Scrabble Club. 2009-04-02. Retrieved 2022-09-24.
  55. ^ section 3.4.1 of the Rules of Procedures for Online Voting
  56. ^ Knight Foundation awards $5000 to best created-on-the-spot projects, June 2009
  57. ^ Kubernetes Community, Kubernetes, 2022-09-24, retrieved 2022-09-24
  58. ^ "Kumoricon ā€“ Mascot Contest". Kumoricon. Retrieved 2022-09-24.
  59. ^ article 8.3 of the bylaws
  60. ^ The Principles of LiquidFeedback. Berlin: Interaktive Demokratie e. V. 2014. ISBN 978-3-00-044795-2.
  61. ^ "Madisonium Bylaws - Adopted". Google Docs.
  62. ^ "Wahlmodus" (in German). Metalab.at. Retrieved 2010-05-08.
  63. ^ David Chandler, Voting for more than just either-or, MIT Tech Talk, volume 52, number 19, page 2, 12 March 2008
  64. ^ See:
  65. ^ "2009 Director Elections". noisebridge.net.
  66. ^ "Online Voting Policy". openembedded.org.
  67. ^ ONNX Steering Committee election guideline
  68. ^ "OpenStack Election ā€” OpenStack Governance". governance.openstack.org. Retrieved 2022-09-24.
  69. ^ Mark, Atwood (May 25, 2016). "[Partners] text of OpenSwitch Project Charter 2016-05-03". Retrieved 2022-09-24.
  70. ^ "Committee Elections 2012". rllmuk. 10 April 2012. Retrieved 2022-09-24.
  71. ^ Squeak Oversight Board Election 2010, March 2010
  72. ^ See:
  73. ^ "[IAEP] Election status update". lists.sugarlabs.org. Retrieved 2022-09-24.
  74. ^ Minutes of the 2018 Annual Sverok Meeting, November 2018
  75. ^ "2007 TopCoder Collegiate Challenge". community.topcoder.com. Retrieved 2022-09-24.
  76. ^ Bell, Alan (May 17, 2012). "Ubuntu IRC Council Position". Retrieved 2022-09-24.
  77. ^ "/v/GAs - Pairwise voting results". vidyagaemawards.com.
  78. ^ See:
  79. ^ "WikipƩdia:Prise de dƩcision/Choix dans les votes", WikipƩdia (in French), 2019-08-22, retrieved 2022-09-24
  80. ^ "Pages liƩes Ơ MƩthode Schulze". fr.wikipedia.org (in French). Retrieved 2022-09-24.
  81. ^ "ויקיפדיה:פ×Øלמנט/הכ×Øעה" [XIV:Parliament/Decisionmaking]. he.wikipedia.org (in Hebrew).
  82. ^ See e.g. here ā€» (May 2009), here ā€» (August 2009), and here ā€» (December 2009).
  83. ^ See here and here.
  84. ^ Š”ŠµŠ²ŃŃ‚Š½Š°Š“цŠ°Ń‚Ń‹Šµ Š²Ń‹Š±Š¾Ń€Ń‹ Š°Ń€Š±ŠøтрŠ¾Š², Š²Ń‚Š¾Ń€Š¾Š¹ тур [Result of Arbitration Committee Elections]. kalan.cc (in Russian). Archived from the original on 2015-02-22.
  85. ^ See here

External linksā€»

Text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution-ShareAlike License. Additional terms may apply.

ā†‘